STUDIES ON SPANISH-PHILIPPINE PRIVATE LAW<br>
Papers of the Private Law of the Philippines and Spain International Scientific Congress

STUDIES ON SPANISH-PHILIPPINE PRIVATE LAW
Papers of the Private Law of the Philippines and Spain International Scientific Congress

Coord.: José Manuel de Torres Perea
Universidad de Málaga

Volver al índice

HOW TO SECURE THE ENFORCEMENT OF PENALTIES
IN INTERNATIONAL COMMERCIAL CONTRACTS

Ignacio Marín García*

Abstract: This paper claims the need of transnational rules to secure the enforcement of penalty clauses in international commercial contracts, since the contractual toolkit that parties may use seems to be insufficient to address both the clash between the civil and the common law traditions, and the existing disparities among civil laws in this area.  The international community acknowledged this need a long time ago, but unfortunately the tremendous effort exerted in many different harmonization projects is unlikely to lead to the certainty that actors in international trade demand.  Nevertheless, instead of transnational rules, the statutory recognition at national level of penalties in international commercial contracts is proposed as the most feasible solution to shield the enforcement of penalties in common law jurisdictions.

Keywords: Contract Penalties, Liquidated Damages, Enforcement, International Commercial Contracts.

Introduction

In the field of penalty clauses, defined as any agreement for the payment of a fixed sum on breach of contract, one of the most distinctive features among civil and common law systems is the extent of the judicial review of the stipulated sum.  While common law courts may declare unenforceable such agreement by virtue of the principle of just compensation, 1 civil law courts may only reduce a grossly excessive stipulated sum.  The agreed sums exceeding the actual loss of the promisee are unlikely to be enforced by Anglo-American judges,2 and those deemed extremely high by Continental European judges are also moderated.  Therefore, broadly speaking, the principle of non-enforcement of contract penalties governs in common law, and the principle of enforcement of penalties subject to reduction controls in civil law.

The main difference between these two legal traditions lies on their different notions about contract liability: in common law systems, the payment of damages constitutes true fulfillment of the contractual promise.  Whereas, in civil law systems, contract liability is an effect arising from the breach or a sanction.3  Thus, for a civil lawyer, the amount stipulated is always intended to be higher than the loss. 4

In a comparative view, the major objection against the common law of penalties is that parties are placed in the worst of all possible scenarios, without the flexibility of enforcement of penalties subject to reduction (most civil law systems), and without the certainty of literal enforcement of penalties (Spain).5   Indeed, from the economic analysis of law, the extreme rigidity of common law courts has been criticized on account of judges disregarding upon these provisions with disfavor, 6 since any judicial review resulting in the unenforcement of penalties threatens the function of this remedy against breach.7   However, in international commercial contracts, the enforcement of those penalties constitutes an even major concern, since uncertainty is much higher due to the applicable law and the court decision when adjudicating the dispute or enforcing a judgment or an arbitration award.

Part I briefly presents the rules governing penalties in three different jurisdictions: a common law jurisdiction, the United States (Section I.1), and two civil law jurisdictions with fundamental distinctions, France and Spain (Section I.2).  Next, Part II denounces the lack of transnational rules to secure the enforcement of penalties in international commercial contracts (Section II.1).  Furthermore, Part II explains why the will of the contracting parties may be at risk in an international litigation or arbitration in the absence of coordination instruments among the several jurisdictions (Section II.2).  Finally, instead of transnational rules, the statutory recognition at national level of penalties in international commercial contracts is proposed in Part II as the most feasible solution to shield the enforcement of penalties in common law jurisdictions (Section II.3).

I. The Civil-Common Law Comparison of Rules Governing Penalties

I.1. United States: the Principle of Non-Enforcement of Penalties

American state laws stick to the common law rule of non-enforcement of penalties.  Liquidation of damages is a permissible method of limiting the defaulting promisor’s liability for compensatory damages: the parties agree at the time of contracting that damages for breach will be limited to a prescribed formula.  Nonetheless, if the stipulated amount entails an undue oppression on the promisor, liquidated damages may be held to be a penalty and, therefore, unenforceable.  This rule has been characterized as anomalous, particularly because contracting parties lack power to bargain over their remedial rights in a legal system in which freedom of contract is a deeply rooted principle.8
The most illustrative case on the American common law of penalties is Banta v. Stamford Motor Co. (1914),9 opinion which firstly delineated the test to determine whether a provision for the payment of a stipulated sum in the event of a breach of contract will be regarded as one for liquidated damages.  This test was formed by three conditions:

These conditions . . . are (1) the damages to be anticipated as resulting from the breach must be uncertain in amount or difficult to prove; (2) there must have been an intent on the part of the parties to liquidate them in advance; and (3) the amount stipulated must be a reasonable one, that is to say, not greatly disproportionate to the presumable loss or injury.10

The subsequent case law further elaborated this test in such a way that the second condition, the intent of the parties, did not survive over time;11 and the third condition has been relaxed in the sense that the reasonableness of the amount stipulated may also be ascertained in the light of both the anticipated or actual loss, instead of only the anticipated loss at the time of contracting (in Banta, the so-called ‘presumable loss’).12

In addition, the difficulty of proof of loss at the moment of contracting still continues as the other relevant factor for the assessment of the reasonability of the amount stipulated, 13 although the ease of proof alone should not be purported to deem the agreed sum as a penalty.14

Hence, American courts apply today one single test of reasonableness with two elements, namely the disproportion of the agreed sum and the difficulty of proof of loss, in order to determine whether a liquidation of damages is a penalty. 15

I.2. Civil Law: the Principle of Enforcement of Penalties Subject to Reduction (France) and the Principle of Literal Enforcement of Penalties (Spain)

The literal enforcement of conventional penalties was a rule of classical Roman law that entitled the aggrieved party to recover the agreed sum without any restriction. 16  In the XIXth century, the codification brought back the principle of literal enforcement of penalty clauses to Continental European laws.17   In this vein, the French Civil Code, as enacted in 1804, established the literal enforcement of conventional penalties in Article 1152:[l]orsque la convention porte que celui qui manquera de l’exécuter paiera une certaine somme à titre de dommages-intérêts, il ne peut être alloué à l’autre partie une somme plus forte ni moindre’. 18  The Napoleonic Code was the model for the neighboring nations (Belgium, Italy, Portugal and Spain) and their laws copied this regulation.  Nonetheless, the liberal Roman principle of literal enforcement of penalties was progressively abandoned,19 and most European legislations converged on allowing the judge to moderate those contract penalties which are grossly excessive.  Thus, the judicial review of penalty clauses on the grounds of equity is the solution widely accepted by Continental European laws, since Germanic legal systems do also opt for it (Austria, Germany and Switzerland). 20

In contrast with the majority of European civil law systems, Spanish law solely allows courts to reduce the penalty whether the breach of contract has less entity that the one anticipated by the contracting parties in the provision,21 so the judicial review on the grounds of equity is excluded. 22  The Spanish Civil Code (Article 1154) imposes on the judge the duty to moderate the penalty if, and only if, the undertaking has been partially or irregularly performed. 23  To moderate the penalty, the judge must assess the proportion between the actual performance and the performance that would have barred the claim of the penalty. 24

Albeit the above mentioned differences concerning the grounds of the judicial review, European civil law systems share the same concept of penalty clause: a provision seeking to deter breach by requiring the payment of extra-compensatory damages.

Beyond the grounds of the judicial review, which serve to classify a civil law system as one of enforcement of penalties subject to reduction or one of literal enforcement of penalties, there exist other minor but significant differences among the several penalty clause regimes pertaining to the civil law tradition.  Next, the French and the Spanish law of penalties are compared in order to point out the most basic traits of each of them.

a) Even though the judicial review under Spanish law is much more restricted, the judicial intervention of the penalty is still exceptional in French law, because the disproportion must be an abuse of the coercive function, being obviously excessive, and having no justification.25

b) While in Spanish law the judicial intervention of the penalty may consist only in the reduction of the sum stipulated, 26 in French law the judge may reduce the penalty if manifestly excessive, or increase it if ridiculously low.27

c) If applicable, Spanish courts must reduce the penalty,28 although the question about the possibility of an ex officio judicial intervention is more debatable. 29  On the contrary, the French Civil Code (Articles 1152 and 1231) authorizes courts to exercise their judicial discretion when reviewing the ‘clause pénale’, once it has been determined that the sum stipulated is manifestly excessive or pitiful and also in the event of partial performance.  Furthermore, in French law, the adjustment of the sum stipulated on the judge’s own motion is statutorily granted, 30 which reinforces the discretionary judicial review of penalties.

In addition, in both legal systems, the question whether to adjust the sum stipulated and in which degree are reviewable by the appellate court but not by the highest court of ordinary jurisdiction, since each of these issues is considered a matter of fact instead of a matter of law.  Therefore, the Spanish Supreme Court may decide these issues only on the basis of the prior finding that the lower court erred in qualifying promisor’s performance. 31  In this regard, the French Cour de cassation balances the stronger discretionary judicial review of penalties with a demanding requirement of accountability, reversing those judgments which alter the sum stipulated without articulating the factual reasons why the amount set fits into the above mentioned category of ‘manifestly excessive’.32

d) The French and the Spanish law of penalties have in common the application of an objective, retrospective test: despite not being entirely consistent, 33 French courts compare the sum stipulated with the actual damages, 34 and Spanish courts the breach anticipated in the provision with the actual breach.35   Whereas, the American common law of penalties and the Uniform Commercial Code provide not only the use of the applicable test retrospectively (reasonableness ex post), but also prospectively (reasonableness ex ante).36   Notwithstanding, in French law, the breaching party’s bad faith in the performance is a relevant factor in the determination of whether a penalty is ‘manifestly excessive’, 37 unlike Spanish law, since this argument does not have any relevance.38

e) Lastly, another significant difference between the French and the Spanish law of penalties is that the former bans the cumulative penalty, i.e. the aggrieved party is not jointly entitled to the payment of penalty and the performance of the obligation,39 while the latter allows the cumulative penalty, as long as this right has been clearly granted. 40  French law makes a single exception: the penalty for breach due to delay, which does not properly constitute a cumulative penalty, because the creditor will never obtain a timely performance of the already lately performed obligation.  In the context of European civil law systems, the cumulative penalty is not a singularity of Spanish law. 41

On a comparative account limited to Western Europe, French law cannot be generalized, and deemed as the European civil law model of contract penalties, due to the judicial power of increasing an unreasonably small agreed sum, since usually the penalty may only be reduced.  Nevertheless, French law features the other characteristics of the wide majority of European civil laws: (1) the validity of contract penalties, which may have the effect of coercing a party to perform her obligation; (2) the judicial review of penalties on the grounds of equity as a discretionary faculty, based on a retrospective test considering the actual harm, or on the grounds of partial performance; and (3) the promisee’s entitlement either to the penalty or to specific performance, with the exception of delay, being deprived of claiming statutory damages.

Regarding this third common characteristic, German law is neither representative: not only the cumulative penalty is permitted, 42 but also the promisee is entitled to claim statutory damages, operating the penalty as the minimum amount of damages.43

In sum, in spite of the common traits already mentioned, there are not uniform rules governing contract penalties in Continental Europe, and historically there has not been a real political will of unifying contract law within the European Union,44 even though some signs of change in 2010. 45  These signs of change led to a highly mature and innovative proposal of contract law harmonization, the Proposal for a Regulation on a Common European Sales Law, 46 the scope of which are those aspects which pose real problems in cross-border transactions without extending to aspects that are best addressed by national laws.  Notwithstanding, this Common European Sales Law proposed by the Commission does not deal with contract penalties.

II. How to Secure the Enforcement of Penalties in International Commercial Contracts
The General Assembly of the United Nations, when recommending the states to consider the adoption of the UNCITRAL Uniform Rules (1983),47 summarized with brilliance the reasons for the harmonization of the conflicting common law and civil law rules governing penalties in the sphere of international commercial contracts:

Recognizing that a wide range of international trade contracts contain clauses obligating a party that fails to perform an obligation under contract to pay an agreed sum to the other party,

Noting that the effect and validity of such clauses are often uncertain owing to disparities in the treatment of such clauses in various legal systems,

Believing that these uncertainties constitute an obstacle to the flow of international trade,

Being of the opinion that it would be desirable for the legal rules applicable to such clauses to be harmonized so as to reduce or eliminate the uncertainties concerning such clauses and remove these uncertainties as a barrier to the flow of international trade,48

II.1. Indetermination or Failure of the International Instruments of Coordination: Treaties and Soft Law

Besides the UNCITRAL Uniform Rules, many other serious attempts have been made to broaden the enforceability of penalties in international trade, but nowadays there are no transnational rules that secure the enforcement of penalties in international commercial contracts.  The lack of transnational rules in this area of law results from both the profound divergence between the civil and the common law traditions, and the relevant differences within the civil law countries.

The Benelux Convention on Penalty Clauses (1973)49 was the earliest and perhaps the most courageous of these attempts, despite being addressed solely to three signatory states (Belgium, Netherlands and Luxemburg), with very similar national laws, and all members of the same regional trade organization.

Afterwards, the question was deliberately skipped in the Vienna Convention (1980),50 the most successful treaty offering uniform commercial law rules.51   In my view, the CISG represented a lost chance to establish a path for the harmonization of contract penalties, given that its sphere of application is well-tailored (Article 1, ‘contracts of sale of goods between parties whose places are in different States’), and parties to a contract may exclude or vary its application (Article 6).

Outside the domain of treaties, a wide variety of instruments have tackled this issue, however, none of them is legally binding for states, albeit potentially useful because parties may designate one of them as applicable law.

In the international arena, the UNCITRAL Uniform Rules (1983) were optimistically accompanied with a draft convention, mirroring the Vienna Convention, 52 even though the UNCITRAL Uniform Rules were never adopted. 53  The UNCITRAL Uniform Rules aimed to find a worldwide standard to balance the civil law enforceability, unless manifestly excessive, and the common law rule of unenforceability.  The UNCITRAL Uniform Rules refer to ‘contract clauses for an agreed sum due upon failure of performance’ and non-sophisticated parties are excluded from its scope (Article 1),54 providing that these clauses are presumptively valid, so the judicial intervention may consist only in the reduction of the agreed sum if ‘substantially disproportionate’ with respect to the actual harm (Article 8). 55  Nevertheless, the civil approach turned out to be predominant, 56 as evidenced by the non-trivial dropping of the ‘genuine pre-estimate’ between the revised draft (Article G) and the definitive version (Article 8).57  For common law countries, the public policy concern against inequitable bargains together with the application by courts of two standards of justice, one for domestic and another for international transactions, or just the lack of interest may explain the failure of the UNCITRAL Uniform Rules.58

In the international arena too, the Unidroit Principles (Article 7.4.13),59 the major instrument of soft law in the field of international commercial contracts, have also resolved the question following the civil law principle of enforcement of penalties subject to reduction:60 after giving an broad definition intended to include both liquidated damages and penalties,61 ‘agreed payment for non-performance’, the general rule is the recoverability of stipulated damages regardless of the actual harm (Article 7.4.13(1)), but the court may reduce those ‘grossly excessive amounts’ (Article 7.4.13(2)).

Within the European context, the scholar-made soft law rules of both the Principles of European Contract Law (Article 9:509),62 and the Draft Common Frame of Reference (Article III-3:712) 63 stuck to the pattern set by the Unidroit Principles: stipulated damages are named again ‘agreed payment for non-performance’ in the PECL, or ‘stipulated payment for non-performance’ in the DCFR, and in the both texts the governing norm is the recoverability of the sum irrespective of the actual harm, unless the court finds it to be ‘grossly excessive’, case in which the sum will be reduced.  The antecedent of them was the Council of Europe Resolution (78) 3,64 a set of eight non-binding rules that the member states were recommended to adopt in order to harmonize the civil law regimes.  

The Council of Europe Resolution (78) 3, considered as a whole, contains much more detailed and elaborated rules than the soft law instruments examined until now (Unidroit Principles, PECL, and DCFR).  Not only for using an inclusive definition of penalty (Article 1), 65 and turning to the principle of enforcement of penalties subject to reduction (Article 7), but also for dealing with the prohibition of cumulative penalties (Article 2), and the compatibility of the penalty with claims for specific performance, statutory damages, and additional damages (Articles 3, 5 and 6).  The impact on the current civil law codes was minimal, since most reforms of the national laws towards the aforementioned principle occurred years before,66 as described in Section I.2.  Nonetheless, the Council of Europe Resolution (78) 3 might be viewed as the European civil law model of contract penalties, given that the main characteristics of European civil laws are captured: (1) the validity of contract penalties, which may have the effect of coercing a party to perform her obligation; (2) the judicial review of penalties on the grounds of equity as a discretionary faculty, based on a retrospective test considering the actual harm, or on the grounds of partial performance; and (3) the promisee’s entitlement either to the penalty or to specific performance, with the exception of delay.

II.2. Fighting Uncertainty: Contractual Arrangements for the Enforceability of Penalties and their Effectiveness

The lack of transnational rules that control the enforceability of penalty clauses in international commercial contracts, as shown in Section II.1, puts at risk the will of the contracting parties.  In addition to this lack of transnational rules, the absence of coordination instruments among the several jurisdictions at a national level 67 entails that parties are unable to secure the enforceability of contract penalties by resorting to the available contractual devices, such as choice of law, forum selection, and arbitration clauses.68   These contractual arrangements might turn out to be ineffective for several reasons, in particular whether the enforcement of the penalty is sought in common law courts, either adjudicating the dispute or executing the judgment or the arbitration award, since the mandatory rules against penalties might never be displaced. 69

Obviously, the effectiveness of these contractual arrangements is likely to be higher when parties have chosen a civil law, and the court involved in adjudication or enforcement is also a civil law one, since general policy considerations that may render the penalty void will not arise so long as lex contractus and lex fori belong to the same legal tradition.  For instance, if parties designate Spanish law as applicable, and the selected forum is Chile.70   Within the European Union, the effectiveness of these clauses is even higher, due to the general rules of international private law in the area of contracts,71 which even allow that parties derogate from certain mandatory rules.  As an illustration, if parties decide to severely limit contract liability by using a penalty clause with an unreasonable small agreed sum, Italian law may be the applicable law designated to trump the French Civil Code (Article 1152) when the selected forum is France in order to prevent the judge from increasing a ridiculously low penalty (‘dérisoire peine’) on the grounds of equity.  The Rome I Regulation (Articles 3.3 and 9.1)72 grants this possibility — only the ‘overriding mandatory provisions’ of the law of forum will resist the law chosen by the parties.  In this regard, this French rule is mandatory, 73 but it can hardly be deemed an ‘overriding mandatory provision’ in accordance with the law of the European Union.

Conversely, the effectiveness of these contractual arrangements is uncertain when the parties intended to avoid the common law prohibition of penalties, and the court deciding the case or enforcing the foreign judgment or arbitral award is a common law court.  The likelihood of success increases in the next order: (1) only a pro-penalty choice of law, (2) a pro-penalty choice of law in conjunction with the selection of a civil law forum, and (3) a pro-penalty choice of law and arbitration in a civil law country, which is the safest way to secure the enforcement of penalties in international commercial contracts.74

However, considering the third solution to secure the enforcement of penalties in common law jurisdictions, one may doubt whether the enforcing court would refuse the recognition and enforcement of the arbitral award, since even the New York Arbitration Convention 75 grants this refusal if the recognition or enforcement would be contrary to the public policy of that country (Article V(2)(b)). 76  This ground under the New York Arbitration Convention casts doubt on the enforcement of an arbitral award in common law countries, in particular, in the United States, one of the jurisdictions analyzed here.  Absent any decision from an American court, there is not a definitive answer to this question yet.  Nevertheless, in accordance with the case law from another common law jurisdiction, the award would be enforced.77

An additional precaution that might be taken, as DiMatteo cleverly suggests,78 is the prepayment of the penalty by means of an escrow account within the jurisdiction of the selected civil law forum, or within the same civil law country agreed for the arbitration.  Notwithstanding, the contract may provide several penalties or penalties of a considerable amount, then none of the potential breaching parties will be prone to deposit the full amount of the penalties stipulated in the contract.  Therefore, albeit the payment of the potentially due penalty is not completely secured, the deposit in the escrow account secures at least the partial payment, acting as well as a powerful incentive to ensure performance.

II.3. A Quick and Safe Solution: To Shield the Enforcement of Penalties in International Commercial Contracts in Common Law Jurisdictions

After having examined prior attempts for the harmonization of the conflicting common law and civil law rules governing penalties, the main reason of the failure of all these harmonization projects (treaties or bodies of soft law) has always been that the root principles of each legal tradition are not compatible, therefore the adoption of one root principle necessarily supersedes the other.  In this regard, treaties and bodies of soft law have usually opted for the principle of enforcement of penalties subject to reduction, the civil law principle, a choice that has involved the understandable rejection of common law countries.  

Under this dilemma, the demand of legal certainty in the field of enforcement of penalty clauses by the actors in international trade points to a relatively easy response: shielding the enforcement of penalties in international commercial contracts in common law jurisdictions by means of their statutory recognition at national level.  Statutory recognition at national level that should be narrowly tailored to penalties expressly agreed by the parties in contracts in which at least one party is non-national, and the choice of law designates a foreign law according to which penalties are permissible.

In my opinion, the proposed solution is the most feasible for the enforceability and effectiveness of penalties in international commercial contracts because (i) it would be unilaterally adopted by each single common law jurisdiction, which implies that it has no coordination costs and that its success does not depend on an agreement among a high number of states; and (ii) it would be legally binding, which of course means a stronger effect than an optional regime designated in a body of soft law.

Nevertheless, there exists the well-founded fear of the rejection of the proposed solution by the legislatives of the common law countries, since it would lead to the application of two standards of justice, one for domestic and another of international transactions.  This reasoning was one of the grounds to turn down the UNCITRAL Uniform Rules.79

Conclusion
After having explored the clash between the civil and the common law traditions, and the existing disparities among civil laws in the field of penalty clauses, this paper urges the adoption of transnational rules to secure the enforcement of penalty clauses in international commercial contracts in order to provide the actors in international trade with the certainty that they demand.

The international community acknowledged this need more than three decades ago, when the first UNCITRAL Draft was submitted in 1981, but the final UNCITRAL Uniform Rules and other harmonization projects have failed in that respect.  Basically, the reasons that might explain this failure are two: on the one hand, all these projects have always aligned with the civil law legal tradition — in particular, the UNCITRAL Uniform Rules —; and, on the other hand, common law countries are unwilling to give up the prohibition of penalties, and tend to be prejudiced against the enforcement of penalties, even when the parties to a contract are merchants.  

In the absence of coordination instruments among the several jurisdictions, the will of the contracting parties is at risk.  Nevertheless, this lack of transnational rules is much more detrimental for the parties if a common law jurisdiction is involved.  Not only civil law jurisdictions usually do not present sharp differences, but also the effectiveness of the contractual arrangements (choice of law, forum selection and arbitration clauses) is generally higher, especially within the European Union.  On the contrary, whether a common law jurisdiction is involved, parties can only fight uncertainty by incurring substantial transaction costs to secure the enforcement of contract penalties, since all the available contractual devices have to be employed to diminish the likelihood of unenforcement.  In this second scenario, the contractual toolkit may turn out to be insufficient, and therefore the need of transnational rules to bridge the gaps between civil and common law systems becomes critical.

Nevertheless, from a practical point of view, given the failure of all the attempts of the international community in the field of the enforcement of penalties, a quick and safe solution is the shielding of the enforcement of penalties in international commercial contracts in common law jurisdictions by means of their statutory recognition at national level.  This recognition in each state would be restricted to penalties expressly agreed by the parties in contracts in which at least one party is non-national, and the choice of law designates a foreign law according to which penalties are permissible.  Paradoxically, despite the need of transnational rules in this realm, the most feasible solution consists of the approval of national rules of limited scope but amazingly positive effects in international trade.

* Attorney at law in Spain, Cuatrecasas. Gonçalves Pereira. LL.M., Columbia Law School (2011), and PhD Candidate, Universitat Pompeu Fabra (Barcelona, Spain).

1 In these jurisdictions, contract law does not aim to force the promisor to perform, but to compensate adequately the aggrieved promisee, E. Allan Farnsworth, Contracts (4th edn, Aspen 2004) 811.  Regarding the principle of just compensation, the holdings of two cases, one American and the other English, are very illustrative of the fact that in common law systems freedom of contract encompasses such a wide autonomy for the parties to enter a contract, but a much more restrictive one to arrange remedies against its breach. First, in Jaquith v Hudson 5 Mich 123 (Mich 1858), the Supreme Court of Michigan stated that ‘courts will not permit the parties by express stipulation, or any form of language, however clear the intent, to set it aside’.  Second, in Addis v Gramophone Co. [1909] AC 488 (HL), the House of Lords insisted that ‘damages for breach of contract [are] in the nature of compensation, not punishment’.

2 Nevertheless, English law and American state laws present substantially different regimes governing liquidation of damages, with respect to the analysis of its validity and the legal consequences for a penalty clause.

3 Judge Holmes noted that ‘the duty to keep a contract at common law means a prediction that you must pay damages if you do not keep it,- nothing else’ (Oliver W Holmes, Jr, ‘The Path of the Law’ (1897) 10 Harv L Rev 457, 477).  See also Fernando Pantaleón Prieto, ‘Las nuevas bases de la responsabilidad contractual’ (1992)46 Anuario de Derecho Civil 1719, 1737-40.

4 Ugo Mattei, ‘The Comparative Law and Economics of Penalty Clauses in Contracts’(1995) 43 Am J Comp Law 427, 428.

5 GH Treitel, Remedies for Breach of Contract. A Comparative Account (Clarendon 1988) 233.

6 Aaron Edlin and Alan Schwartz, ‘Optimal Penalties in Contracts’ (2003) 78Chi-Kent L Rev 33, 37.  See also Steven Walt, ‘Penalty Clauses and Liquidated Damages’, Encyclopedia of Law and Economics (2d edn, 2011) vol 6,178, defending that the wrong conviction that courts are capable of determining the value of contract performance for the promisee explains the judicial review of liquidated damages in common law systems.

7 The selective enforcement of these provisions is controversial not only for economic efficiency reasons, but also for reasons of fairness.  Phillip R Kaplan, ‘A Critique of the Penalty Limitation on Liquidated Damages’ (1978) 50S Cal L Rev1055, 1071-72; James Arthur Weisfield, ‘“Keep the Change!”: A Critique of the No Actual Injury Defense to Liquidated Damages’ (1990) 65Wash L Rev977, 993-95.  In the United States, the unequal treatment of very similar cases bags the question about the real set of rules applied by courts.  See also Elizabeth Warren, ‘Formal and Operative Rules Under Common Law and Code’ (1983)30UCLA L Rev898 , dealing with loss above the stipulated sum; Ann Morales Olazábal, ‘Formal and Operative Rules in Overliquidation Per Se Cases’ (2004) 41Am Bus LJ 503, examining cases of absence of loss.  Moreover, under highly discretionary judicial review of contract penalties, parties would prefer to directly let the ascertainment of damages to courts instead of setting them in advance. Aída Kemelmajer de Carlucci, La Cláusula Penal (Depalma 1981) 109.

8 Joseph M Perillo, Calamari and Perillo on Contracts (6th edn, West 2009) 531; Farnsworth (n 1) 811.  See also Robert A. Hillman, ‘The Limits of Behavioral in Legal Analysis. The Case of Liquidated Damages’ (2000) 85Cornell L Rev717, 733-38, arguing that agreed damages provisions must be subject to judicial scrutiny but treated like any other contract term; Larry DiMatteo, ‘A Theory of Efficient Penalty: Eliminating the Law of Liquidated Damages’ (2000) 38 Am Bus LJ 633, 733, defending the same claim.

9 Banta v Stamford Motor Co. 92 A 665 (Conn 1914), the Supreme Courts of Errors of Connecticut upheld as a valid liquidation of damages the agreed sum of $15 a day for delay in the delivery of a luxury yacht priced at $5,500.

10 ibid 667-68.

11 Restatement (Second) of Contracts § 356 cmt c (1981): ‘Neither the parties’ actual intention as to its validity nor their characterization of the term as one for liquidated damages or a penalty is significant in determining whether the term is valid’.  See also Wassenaar v Panos 331 N.W.2d 357 (Wis 1983), ruling the Supreme Court of Wisconsin that the ‘subjective intent of the parties has little bearing on whether the clause is objectively reasonable’; Farnsworth (n 1) 817, explaining that the inquiry goes to whether the effect of upholding the stipulation improperly compels performance; Joseph M Perillo, Corbin on Contracts, vol 11 (11th edn, Lexis Nexis 2005) 427, stating that, even in those jurisdictions which formally keep intention as an independent factor, intention is derived from an objective test, so this prong of the test is redundant.

12 This clash between the classical requirement that the sum must be a genuine pre-estimate of the harm (reasonableness ex ante) and the alternative that the sum must be reasonable at the time of breach when compared with the actual harm (reasonableness ex post) remains unsolved.  In this vein, the Restatements have never opted for one of them, and the Uniform Commercial Code either. Restatement (First) of Contracts § 339(1) (1932), without referring to any of the two criteria; Restatement (Second) of Contracts § 356 cmt b (1981), explicitly admitting both criteria, albeit acknowledging that each one leads to different results; UCC § 2-718(1) (1977).

13 Restatement (Second) of Contracts § 356 cmt b (1981): ‘If the difficulty of proof of loss is great, considerable latitude is allowed in the approximation of anticipated or actual harm. If, on the other hand, the difficulty of proof of loss is slight, less latitude is allowed in that approximation’.

14 Dan B Dobbs, Law of Remedies, vol 3 (2nd edn, West 1993) 251, claiming that this is the right interpretation of Restatement (Second) of Contracts § 356(1) (1981); William D Hawkland, Uniform Commercial Code Series § 2-718:03, vol 2 (Clark Boardman Callaghan 1994), with respect to the UCC § 2-718(1) (1977), advocating that, in contrast with other common law jurisdictions, the difficulty of proof of loss at the moment of contracting has never been a requirement for the validity of the agreed damages clause in American contract law.

15 In comparison with the above mentioned sections of both Restatements, the UCC § 2-718(1) (1977) added a new parameter, ‘the inconvenience or nonfeasibility of otherwise obtaining an adequate remedy’.  Although incorporated into state laws, courts rarely apply this additional factor.  In fact, the American Law Institute has declared that the factors enumerated by the UCC do not operate as independent requirements for the validity of the clause, Motion Concerning Section 2-718(1) (May 11, 2001).  See also Hawkland (n 14) § 2-718:04, arguing that the inclusion of this third factor is reiterative, since the difficulty of proof of loss already points to the availability of other adequate remedies; Ian R Macneil, ‘Power of Contract and Agreed Remedies’ (1962) 47 Cornell L Q 495, 528, asserting that historically court decisions had conferred great importance to this third additional factor when examining the validity of agreed remedies clauses.

16 Paulus (D. 44, 7, 44, 6).

17 The Justinian Code (C. 7, 47) limited the amount of damages claimable to the double of the value of what had been promised.  Ius commune was also influenced by Canon law, which considered an unjustified gain those amounts that punished with severity the party in breach. Aristides N. Hatzis, ‘Having the Cake and Eating It Too. Efficient Penalty Clauses in Common Law and Civil Contract Law’ (2003) 22 Int’l Rev L & Econ 381, 399.  Seealso Reinhard Zimmermann, The Law of Obligations: Roman Foundations of the Civilian Tradition (OUP 1996) 95-113.

18 ‘Where an agreement provides that the party who fails to perform it will pay a certain sum as damages, the other party may not be awarded a greater or lesser sum’, French Civil Code <http://www.legifrance.gouv.fr>.

19 The Italian Civil Code enacted in 1942 (Article 1384); the Portuguese Civil Code enacted in 1966 (Article 812); and in Belgium, without any statutory reform, after the Belgian Cour de cassation Judgment, 24 November 24, the case law considers that extravagant contract penalties are against the public order and, for this reason, void.  In 1975, the French Civil Code was reformed too.  Law No 75-597 of 9 July 1975, JO 10 July 1975 7076, added a second paragraph to Article 1152: ‘Néanmoins, le juge peut modérer ou augmenter la peine qui avait été convenue, si elle est manifestement excessive ou dérisoire. Toute stipulation contraire sera réputée non écrite’ (‘Nevertheless, the judge may moderate or increase the agreed penalty, where it is obviously excessive or ridiculously low. Any stipulation to the contrary shall be deemed unwritten’, French Civil Code <http://www.legifrance.gouv.fr>).  This article let the judge to increase or decrease a penalty found to be disproportionate.  Moreover, Law No 75-597reformed Article 1231, governing the reduction of the penalty in case of partial performance, stating that Article 1152 was also applicable: ‘Lorsque l'engagement a été exécuté en partie, la peine convenue peut être diminuée par le juge à proportion de l'intérêt que l'exécution partielle a procuré au créancier, sans préjudice de l'application de l'article 1152. Toute stipulation contraire sera réputée non écrite’ (‘Where an undertaking has been performed in part, the agreed penalty may be lessened by the judge in proportion to the interest which the part performance has procured for the creditor, without prejudice to the application of Article 1152. Any stipulation to the contrary shall be deemed not written’, French Civil Code <http://www.legifrance.gouv.fr>).  Therefore, the same penalty might be reviewed by a French judge on the grounds of partial performance and on the grounds of equity.

20 German Civil Code (BGB § 343), although the German Commercial Code (HGB § 348) excludes contracts between professionals in the scope of their activity.  Both Austrian law (§ 1336.2 Austrian Civil Code, ABGB) and Swiss law (Article 163-3 Code des obligations) admit the judicial review of disproportionate penalties too, but without a different regime for commercial contracts.

21 Fernando Gómez Pomar, ‘El Incumplimiento Contractual en Derecho Español’ (2007) 3 InDret 29 <http://www.indret.com/pdf/466_es.pdf>.  However, in lieu of the Spanish Civil Code, Navarrese civil law may apply, which is the only particular civil law of the Autonomous Communities with its own rules in the field of contract penalties.  Actually, under Navarrese civil law, the coercive function of the penalty is especially protected, since the New Navarrese Code of Laws (Article 518) expressly provides that ‘the agreed penalty should not be reduced by judicial discretion’, so the penalty would not be adjusted on any ground, Navarra Superior Court Judgments, 27 January 2004 (RJ, No 2668), and 9 November 2005 (RJ, No 2006\377).  See also José Ignacio Bonet Sánchez, ‘La cláusula penal’ in Ubaldo Nieto Carol and José Ignacio Bonet Sánchez (eds), Tratado de Garantías en la Contratación Mercantil, vol 1(Civitas 1996) 887, 964-65.  Recall that the Superior Courts of those Autonomous Communities with particular civil law have jurisdiction to adjudicate cases in which arise an issue related to the corresponding particular civil law.

22 The Spanish Supreme Court has constantly rejected the judicial review of penalty clauses on the grounds of equity, STS, 15 October 2008 (RJ, No 5692), STS 17 January 2012 (RJ, No 287), and STS, 10 March 2014 (RJ, No 1467).  However, among other relevant changes, a tentative draft bill aimed to explicitly introduce the judicial review on the grounds of equity, Comisión General de Codificación, Propuesta de Anteproyecto de Ley de Modernización del Derecho de Obligaciones y Contratos (2009), Article 1150.  Within Spanish legal scholars, the majority position has always defended the need of a law reform that allows the judicial review of penalty clauses on the grounds of equity, María Dolores Mas Badía, La Revisión Judicial de las Cláusulas Penales (Tirant Lo Blanch 1995) 216; Isabel Espín Alba, Cláusula Penal. Especial Referencia a la Moderación de la Pena (Marcial Pons 1997) 86.  In this regard, pointing out that the current Article 1154 of the Spanish Civil Code (n 23) excludes judicial review of contract penalties on the grounds of equity, Silvia Díaz Alabart, La Cláusula Penal (Reus 2011) 108-9.  Nonetheless, a minority position had advocated the referred Article 1154 embraces judicial review on the grounds of equity, since the single requirement for the reduction is the disproportion between the penalty and the actual harm, Francisco Jordano Fraga, La Resolución por Incumplimiento en la Compraventa Inmobiliaria. Estudio Jurisprudencial del Artículo 1504 del Código Civil (Civitas 1992) 199-200; José Miguel Rodríguez Tapia, ‘Sobre la Cláusula Penal en el Código Civil’ (1993),46 Anuario de Derecho Civil 511, 578-80.

23 Article 1154: ‘El Juez modificará equitativamente la pena cuando la obligación principal hubiera sido en parte o irregularmente cumplida por el deudor’ (‘The Judge shall proportionately modify the penalty where the principal obligation should have been performed partially or irregularly by the debtor’, Spanish Civil Code <http://www.mjusticia.es/cs/Satellite/es/1215198252168/DetalleInformacion.html).

24 Manuel Albaladejo García, Comentarios al Código Civil y a las Compilaciones Forales, vol 15(2) (Edersa 1983) 486. In consequence, there would be no moderation if the penalty was agreed upon the partial performance actually occurred, STS, 14 September 2007 (RJ, No 5307).

25 Geneviève Viney and Patrice Jourdain, Traité de Droit Civil. Les Effets de la Responsabilité 486-89 (2d edn, LGDJ 2001).

26 Cristina Guilarte Martín-Calero, La Moderación de la Culpa por los Tribunales (Estudio Doctrinal y Jurisprudencial) (Lex Nova 1999) 139.

27 Article 1152 of the French Civil Code (n 19).  Actually, this judicial power to increase the agreed sum when ridiculously low constitutes a distinctive feature of French law in comparison with other European civil law systems.  Unlike other regimes of contract penalties from the decade of the 70s (n 41) only the 1975 reform of the French Civil Code grants this faculty to the courts. Jean Thilmany, ‘Fonctions et Révisibilité Des Clauses Pénales en Droit Comparé’ (1980) 32 Revue Internationale de Droit Comparé 17, 40-1.

28 Article 1154 of the Spanish Civil Code (n 23).  The Spanish Supreme Court finally settled this historical controversy with consistent case law since mid 80s, STS, 7 February 2002 (RJ, No 2887).

29 The Spanish Supreme Court has ruled so in some scattered decisions, being the last one STS, 12 December 1996 (RJ, No 8976).  However, there is a tension with the rules of civil procedure, since an ex officio judicial intervention would imply a judicial action beyond the claims raised by the litigants, Luis Díez-Picazo y Ponce de León, Fundamentos del Derecho Civil Patrimonial, vol 2 (6th edn, Civitas 2008) 468.  See also Charles Calleros, ‘Punitive Damages, Liquidated Damages, and Clauses Pénales in Contract Actions: A Comparative Analysis of the American Common Law and the French Civil Code’ (2006) 32 Brooklyn J Int’l L 67, 104-5, pointing out the same concern with respect to ex officio judicial review of penalties in French law, as mentioned below.

30 Law No 85-1097 of 11 October 1985, JO 15 October 1985 11982, amended both Articles 1152 and 1231 of the French Civil Code, introducing the expression ‘méme d’office’ (‘even of his own motion’).

31 STS, 20 December 2006 (RJ, No 2007/388), and STS, 20 September 2006 (RJ, No 8401).

32 Cass 3e civ, 12 January 2011, Pourvoi No 09-70.262, <http://www.legifrance.gouv.fr/initRechJuriJudi.do>; Cass 3e civ, 13 July 2010, Pourvoi No 09-68.191 <http://www.legifrance.gouv.fr/initRechJuriJudi.do>; Cass 3e civ, 12 January 2010, Pourvoi No 09-11.856 <http://www.legifrance.gouv.fr/initRechJuriJudi.do>; Cass 1e civ, 28 November 2007, Pourvoi No 05-17.927 <http://www.legifrance.gouv.fr/initRechJuriJudi.do>.

33 Calleros (n 29) 105.

34 Denis Mazeaud, La Notion de Clause Pénale (LGDJ 1998) 57-58.

35 Gómez Pomar (n 21).

36 Restatement (First) of Contracts § 339(1) (1932); Restatement (Second) of Contracts § 356 cmt b (1981); UCC § 2-718(1) (1977) (n 12).

37 Calleros (n 29) 106, specifying that the Cour de cassation rejects the behavior of the parties as the sole basis to find a penalty manifestly excessive, Cass com, 11 February 1997, Bull civ II, No 47.

38 However, some scholars have defended the use of the argument of the bad faith to expand the grounds on which the reduction of the penalty is permitted, Jaime Santos Briz, ‘Comentario a los arts. 1152 a 1155 CC’ in Ignacio Sierra Gil de la Cuesta (ed), Comentario al Código Civil, vol 6 (Bosch 2000) 289, 296-97.  Against, María Corona Quesada González, ‘Estudio de la Jurisprudencia del Tribunal Supremo sobre la Pena Convencional’ (2003) 14 Aranzadi Civil 45, arguing that the claim of the sum stipulated may not be deemed against the good faith, since contract penalties are allowed in Spanish law.

39 Article 1229 of the French Civil Code: ‘Il [le créancier] ne peut demander en même temps le principal et la peine, à moins qu'elle n'ait été stipulée pour le simple retard’ (‘He [the creditor] may not claim at the same time the principal and the penalty, unless it was stipulated for a mere delay’, French Civil Code <http://www.legifrance.gouv.fr>).

40 Article 1153 of the Spanish Civil Code: ‘Tampoco el acreedor podrá exigir conjuntamente el cumplimiento de la obligación y la satisfacción de la pena, sin que esta facultad le haya sido claramente otorgada’ (‘Neither may the creditor request jointly the performance of the obligation and the payment of the penalty, unless this power has been clearly granted’, Spanish Civil Code <http://www.mjusticia.es/cs/Satellite/es/1215198252168/DetalleInformacion.html>).

41 German Civil Code (BGB § 341(1)), allowing the claim of performance in addition to the payable penalty when the penalty was promised for improper performance.  On the contrary, following the French solution, the Italian Civil Code (Article 1383), the Portuguese Civil Code (Article 811), and the Austrian Civil Code (§ 1336.1 ABGB), including this latter the non-compliance with the promised place of performance too.  In accordance with French law, the mandatory prohibition of the cumulative penalty is the solution recommended by the Council of Europe, Committee of Ministers Resolution (78) 3 Relating to Penal Clauses in Civil Law (1978) [hereinafter Council of Europe Resolution (78) 3], Article 2: ‘The promisee may not obtain concurrently performance of the principal obligation, as specified in the contract, and payment of the sum stipulated in the penal clause unless that sum was stipulated for delayed performance. Any stipulation to the contrary shall be void’.  In fact, the cumulative penalty is not permitted in the tentative draft bill for the reform of the Spanish Civil Code (n 22) Article 1149; Isabel Arana de la Fuente, ‘Algunas Precisiones sobre la Reforma de la Cláusula Penal en la Propuesta de Modernización del Código Civil en Materia de Obligaciones y Contratos’ (2010) 4 InDret 8-9 <http://www.indret.com/pdf/775_es.pdf>.  Notwithstanding, shortly before the Council of Europe Resolution (78) 3, the Common Provisions Annexed to the Benelux Convention on Penalty Clauses (1973) Article 2(1)-(2), contained the exclusion of the cumulative penalty but as a default rule instead of mandatory, being excludable by the parties’ agreement, Thilmany (n 27) 41.  The exclusion of the cumulative penalty unless otherwise stipulated by the parties was also the solution adopted by the UN Commission on International Trade Law [UNCITRAL] in the Text of Draft Uniform Rules on Liquidated Damages and Penalty Clauses, together with a Commentary thereon (1981) UN Doc A/CN.9/218 [hereinafter UNCITRAL Draft] Article E: ‘(2) Where the agreed sum is to be recoverable or forfeited on non-performance, or defective performance other than delay, the obligee is entitled either to performance, or to recover or forfeit the agreed sum, unless the agreed sum cannot reasonably be regarded as a substitute for performance. (3) The rules set forth above shall not prejudice any contrary agreement made by the parties’.  Despite acknowledging that the cumulation of the two remedies might unjustly enrich the obligee in some circumstances, the Revised Text of Draft Uniform Rules on Liquidated Damages and Penalty Clauses (1983) UN Doc A/CN.9/235 [hereinafter UNCITRAL Revised Draft], this revised draft of uniform rules does not follow the recommendation of the Council of Europe: Article E(3) was deleted, but Article E(2) was amended by including an exception under which the obligee is entitled to performance and the agreed sum when proving that the later cannot reasonably substitute the former, and Article X was added, providing that ‘[t]he parties may by agreement only derogate from or vary the effect of articles D, E and F of this (Convention)(law)’.  See also the final endorsement of this solution, contrary to the recommendation of the Council of Europe, Uniform Rules on Contract Clauses for an Agreed Sum Due upon Failure of Performance (1983) UN Doc A/CN.9/243 [hereinafter UNCITRAL Uniform Rules] Annex I, Articles 6(2) and 9.

42 German Civil Code (BGB § 341(1)).

43 ibid BGB §§ 340(2) and 341(2), both referring to the obligee’s assertion of additional damage in cases of non-performance and defective performance.  Swiss law (Article 161-2 Code des obligations) also allows the recovery of the additional damage.

44 The European Union lacks a general legislative competence in contract law, since its competence is limited to those areas related to consumer protection, which has been extensively exercised (the so-called consumer acquis).  The enactment of a European Civil Code may be perceived as an expression of European identity, but this view is conflicting with the widespread opinion that national codes reflect their own national legal values and legal cultures, factor which explains the political opposition to move towards to the unification of private law, Simon Whittaker, ‘The ‘Draft Common Frame of Reference’. An Assessment’ (2008) 23-4 <http://www.justice.gov.uk/publications/eu-contract-law-common-frame-reference.htm>.  The origin of the Europeanization of private law has scholarly roots, since the 1980s academics from different European countries formed research groups to embark on the harmonization of private law.  Despite the shy institutional support that firstly arrived from the European Parliament, the series of Resolutions from 1986 to 2003, the Commission on European Contract Law, chaired by Professor Ole Lando, elaborated the Principles of European Contract Law [hereinafter PECL], meant to provide black letter rules of soft law using the drafting style of a restatement rather than a code in the civil law meaning of the term, Ole Lando and Huge Beale (eds), Principles of European Contract Law, Parts I and II, Combined and Revised (Kluwer Law International 2000); Ole Lando, Eric Clive, André Prüm and Reinhard Zimmermann (eds), Principles of European Contract Law, Part III (Kluwer Law International 2003).  The second great achievement of this arduous process was the Draft Common Frame of Reference [hereinafter DCFR], commissioned by the European Commission, which combined rules from the PECL, rules from the existing European acquis, and rules from several teams of academics, Christian von Bar, Eric Clive and Hans Schulte-Nölke (eds), Principles, Definitions and Model Rules of European Private Law: Draft Common Frame of Reference (Sellier 2008).  See also Luisa Antoniolli and Francesca Fiorentini (eds), A Factual Assessment of the Draft Common Frame of Reference (Sellier 2010) 7-10.

45 These signs of change were the setting up of the Expert Group to review the DCFR for the European legislation harmonization in the matter of contract law, Commission Decision No 2010/233 [2010] OJ L105 119, and the launch of a public consultation, ‘Commission Green Paper on Policy Options for Progress towards a European Contract Law for Consumers and Businesses’ COM (2010) 348 final.  See also Fernando Gómez Pomar and Marian Gili Saldaña, ‘El Futuro Instrumento Opcional del Derecho Contractual Europeo: Una Breve Introducción a las Cuestiones de Formación, Interpretación, Contenido y Efectos’ (2012) 1 InDret 4-13 <http://www.indret.com/pdf/872_es.pdf>.

46 Commission, ‘Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council on a Common European Sales Law’ COM (2011) 635 final.  This proposal made by the Commission coincides with the widespread thinking according to which the most likely is that an European Regulation adopts, totally or partially, a harmonized body of rules as an optional instrument which contracting parties may choose as the applicable law to their contract in order to opt out of their national laws (the so-called ‘blue button’), Hans Schulte-Nölke, ‘EC Law on the Formation of Contract—from the Common Frame of Reference to the “Blue Button”’ (2007) 3 European Review of Contract Law 332, 348-49.

47 See n 41.

48 General Asseembly, Resolution 38/135 (1983) 270, UN Doc A/RES/38/135.

49 Of course, the legality of contract penalties was not a controversial issue.  This Convention deals with other questions such as the statute of limitations (Article 7). See n 41.

50 United Nations Convention on Contracts for the International Sale of Goods (1980) 1489 UNTS 3 [hereinafter CISG]. Farnsworth (n 1) 812, n 5: ‘Because of the wide gulf between common law systems and other legal systems, the Vienna Convention contains no provision on the important subject of stipulated damages’.

51 Bruno Zeller, CISG and the Unification of International Trade Law (Routledge 2007) 94, in spite of relevant absences like Brazil, India, and United Kingdom.

52 Draft United Nations Convention on Contract Clauses for an Agreed Sum Due upon Failure of Performance (1983) UN Doc A/CN.9/243, Annex II.

53 Jonathan S Solórzano, ‘An Uncertain Penalty: A Look at the International Community’s Inability to Harmonize the Law of Liquidated Damages and Penalty Clauses’ (2009) 15 Law & Bus Rev Am 779, 813: ‘What is clear, however, is that somehow the proposal died.  Model law or convention was ever adopted or entered into . . . The question we are left is why?’.

54 Article 1 of UNCITRAL Uniform Rules: ‘These Rules apply to international contracts in which the parties have agreed that, upon a failure of performance by one party (the obligor), the other party (the obligee) is entitled to an agreed sum from the obligor, whether as a penalty or as compensation’ (emphasis added).

55 Article 8 of UNCITRAL Uniform Rules: ‘The agreed sum shall not be reduced by a court or arbitral tribunal unless the agreed sum is substantially disproportionate in relation to the loss that has been suffered by the obligee’.

56 Against, Larry A DiMatteo, ‘Enforcement of Penalty Clauses: A Civil-Common Law Comparison’ (2010) 5 Internationales Handelsrecht 193, 199, for whom the UNCITRAL Uniform Rules had a ‘middle ground approach’, arguing that ‘[b]y using the word “disproportionate” the Rules adopt the disproportionate standard found in American law and provides a wider scope to the voiding or reforming of penalty clauses in the civil law’, statement which ignores the relatively higher familiarity with the term “disproportionate” or equivalent ones in civil law.

57 Solórzano (n 53) 811-12.  Article G of UNCITRAL Revised Draft: ‘(1) The agreed sum shall not be reduced by a court or arbitral tribunal. (2) However, the agreed sum may be reduced if it is shown to be grossly disproportionate in relation to the loss that has been suffered by the obligee, and if the agreed sum cannot reasonably be regarded as a genuine pre-estimate by the parties of the loss likely to be suffered by the obligee’.  Nonetheless, already in the UNCITRAL Revised Draft, the prevailing view was that this element was not required for reduction, see UNCITRAL Revised Draft (n 41) 13, n 29.

58 Solórzano (n 53) 804 and 813-14.  The general lack of interest is a highly plausible explanation, especially regarding the common law countries, since only eighteen countries responded when the UNCITRAL Draft was circulated, and only one of them was a true common law country (Canada).

59 International Institute for the Unification of Private Law, Unidroit Principles of International Commercial Contracts (1994) [hereinafter Unidroit Principles].  The Article dealing with contract penalties (7.4.13) has the same content in both the 2004 version and the 2010 version of the Unidroit Principles.  Article 7.4.13 Unidroit Principles: ‘(1) Where the contract provides that a party who does not perform is to pay a specified sum to the aggrieved party for such non- performance, the aggrieved party is entitled to that sum irrespective of its actual harm. (2) However, notwithstanding any agreement to the contrary the specified sum may be reduced to a reasonable amount where it is grossly excessive in relation to the harm resulting from the non-performance and to the other circumstances’.

60 DiMatteo (n 56) 199.

61 Ewan McKendrick, ‘Article 74.13’ in Stefan Vogenauer and Jan Kleinheisterkamp (eds), Commentary on the Unidroit Principles of International Commercial Contracts (PICC) (OUP 2009) 919, 923.  See also Michael Joachim Bonell (ed), The Unidroit Principles in Practice. Caselaw and Bibliography on the Unidroit Principles of International Commercial Contracts (2nd edn, Transnational Publishers 2006) 342.

62 Seen 44.  Article 9:509: ‘(1) Where the contract provides that a party who fails to perform is to pay a specified sum to the aggrieved party for such non-performance, the aggrieved party shall be awarded that sum irrespective of its actual loss. (2) However, despite any agreement to the contrary the specified sum may be reduced to a reasonable amount where it is grossly excessive in relation to the loss resulting from the non-performance and the other circumstances’.

63 See n 44.  Article III-3:712: ‘(1) Where the terms regulating an obligation provide that a debtor who fails to perform the obligation is to pay a specified sum to the creditor for such non-performance, the creditor is entitled to that sum irrespective of the actual loss. (2) However, despite any provision to the contrary, the sum so specified in a contract or other juridical act may be reduced to a reasonable amount where it is grossly excessive in relation to the loss resulting from the non-performance and the other circumstances’.

64 See n 41.

65 Arana de la Fuente (n 41) 6.

66 Against, DiMatteo (n 56) 199, defending the influence of the Resolution in the later legislation regarding the generalization of the ‘manifestly excessive’ standard and the preference for reformation or reduction of the stipulated damages.

67 Besides transnational rules, coordination instruments might also be unilaterally provided by purely national rules, for instance, by granting the application of the foreign penalty law designated by the parties, or by granting the execution of a foreign judgment or arbitral award.

68 Pure drafting techniques intended to increase the chances of enforceability of penalty clause if a common law regime is applicable are not considered here, because these techniques are not capable to provide a minimum level of certainty under the case-by-case approach and the selective enforcement of stipulated damages.  See n 7.  See also DiMatteo (n 56) 200-01, making useful suggestions for drafting a penalty clause under American state laws.

69 Farnsworth (n 1) 812, n 5, fearing that soft law may not derogate from this common law prohibition, albeit designated as applicable law by the parties: ‘Whether this provision [Article 7.4.13 Unidroit Principles] can have any effect on a mandatory rule such as the common law rule prohibiting penalties is an open question’.

70 In the example, the parties of an international commercial contract intended the literal enforcement of the agreed penalty, avoiding the objective limit for pecuniary obligations imposed by the Chilean Civil Code (Article 1544), i.e. the penalty may not exceed the double of the value of the undertaking not performed.

71 In the realm of contract law, Council Regulation (EC) 44/2001 on jurisdiction and the recognition and enforcement of judgments in civil and commercial matters (Brussels I) [2001] OJ L12; European Parliament and Council Regulation 593/2008 on the law applicable to contractual obligations (Rome I) [2008] OJ L177.

72 Article 3.3 of Rome I Regulation: ‘A contract shall be governed by the law chosen by the parties. The choice shall be made expressly or clearly demonstrated by the terms of the contract or the circumstances of the case. By their choice the parties can select the law applicable to the whole or to part only of the contract’.  Article 9.1 of Rome I Regulation: ‘Overriding mandatory provisions are provisions the respect for which is regarded as crucial by a country for safeguarding its public interests, such as its political, social or economic organisation, to such an extent that they are applicable to any situation falling within their scope, irrespective of the law otherwise applicable to the contract under this Regulation’.  See Ana Quiñones Escámez, ‘Ley Aplicable a los Contratos Internacionales en la Propuesta de Reglamento “Roma I” de 15.12.2005’ (2006) 3 InDret 16-7 <http://www.indret.com/pdf/367_es.pdf>, explaining the origin and evolution of the concept of overriding mandatory provisions (leyes de policía) in the case law of the Court of Justice of the European Communities.

73 Article 1152 of the French Civil Code (n 19), providing that ‘[a]ny stipulation to the contrary shall be deemed unwritten’.

74 DiMatteo (n 56) 200, sharing the same view in this regard, despite a more pessimistic opinion about the enforcement of the award in the United States.

75 Convention on the Recognition and Enforcement of Foreign Arbitral Awards (1958) 21 UNST 2518 [hereinafter New York Arbitration Convention].

76 Article V(2)(b) of the New York Arbitration Convention: ‘Recognition and enforcement of an arbitral award may also be refused if the competent authority in the country where recognition and enforcement is sought finds that . . . (b) The recognition or enforcement of the award would be contrary to the public policy of that country’.

77 Dirk Otto and Omaia Elwan, ‘Article V(2)’ in Herbert Kronke et alii (eds), Recognition and Enforcement of Foreign Arbitral Awards. A Global Commentary on the New York Convention (Kluwer Law International 2010) 345, 401 n 268, referring to a very recent Hong Kong court decision ruling that the Danish arbitration award providing for overcompensatory liquidated damages does not violate public policy, A v R [2009] HKCFI 342 (Court of First Instance of the High Court, Hong Kong).  Against, DiMatteo (n 56) 200, sustaining that the award is likely to be questioned by American courts.

78 ibid 202.

79 Solórzano (n 53) 804 and 813-4.